Ready for Take-off? The Economic Effects of Regional
Transcrição
Ready for Take-off? The Economic Effects of Regional
RUHR ECONOMIC PAPERS Philipp Breidenbach Ready for Take-off? The Economic Effects of Regional Airport Expansion #549 Imprint Ruhr Economic Papers Published by Ruhr-Universität Bochum (RUB), Department of Economics Universitätsstr. 150, 44801 Bochum, Germany Technische Universität Dortmund, Department of Economic and Social Sciences Vogelpothsweg 87, 44227 Dortmund, Germany Universität Duisburg-Essen, Department of Economics Universitätsstr. 12, 45117 Essen, Germany Rheinisch-Westfälisches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung (RWI) Hohenzollernstr. 1-3, 45128 Essen, Germany Editors Prof. Dr. Thomas K. Bauer RUB, Department of Economics, Empirical Economics Phone: +49 (0) 234/3 22 83 41, e-mail: [email protected] Prof. Dr. Wolfgang Leininger Technische Universität Dortmund, Department of Economic and Social Sciences Economics – Microeconomics Phone: +49 (0) 231/7 55-3297, e-mail: [email protected] Prof. Dr. Volker Clausen University of Duisburg-Essen, Department of Economics International Economics Phone: +49 (0) 201/1 83-3655, e-mail: [email protected] Prof. Dr. Roland Döhrn, Prof. Dr. Manuel Frondel, Prof. Dr. Jochen Kluve RWI, Phone: +49 (0) 201/81 49 -213, e-mail: [email protected] Editorial Office Sabine Weiler RWI, Phone: +49 (0) 201/81 49 -213, e-mail: [email protected] Ruhr Economic Papers #549 Responsible Editor: Roland Döhrn All rights reserved. Bochum, Dortmund, Duisburg, Essen, Germany, 2015 ISSN 1864-4872 (online) – ISBN 978-3-86788-627-7 The working papers published in the Series constitute work in progress circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comments. Views expressed represent exclusively the authors’ own opinions and do not necessarily reflect those of the editors. Ruhr Economic Papers #549 Philipp Breidenbach Ready for Take-off? The Economic Effects of Regional Airport Expansion Bibliografische Informationen der Deutschen Nationalbibliothek Die Deutsche Bibliothek verzeichnet diese Publikation in der deutschen Nationalbibliografie; detaillierte bibliografische Daten sind im Internet über: http://dnb.d-nb.de abrufbar. Das RWI wird vom Bund und vom Land Nordrhein-Westfalen gefördert. http://dx.doi.org/10.4419/86788627 ISSN 1864-4872 (online) ISBN 978-3-86788-627-7 Philipp Breidenbach1 Ready for Take-off? The Economic Effects of Regional Airport Expansion Abstract This paper analyzes whether the expansion of regional airports in Germany caused positive spillover effects on the surrounding economies, exploiting the deregulation of the European aviation market as a quasi-experiment. Such potential spillovers are often used as an argument for the substantial annual subsidies to airports. Previous evaluations often suffer from the problem of reverse causality, since investment decisions are based on the economic conditions of the region. By contrast, the aviation deregulation under the Single European Market-initiative provides an exogenous incentive for investing in the expansion of existing regional airports. A differencein-differences approach is used to estimate the causal effects of this expansion on regional growth. The results are sobering, though, as there is no evidence for any positive spillover effects. JEL Classification: R51, R42, H54 Keywords: Infrastructure investment; regional growth; airport effects April 2015 1 RWI and RUB – I am grateful to Thomas K. Bauer, Roland Döhrn, Corinna Hentschker, Michael Kind, Alfredo Paloyo, Christoph M. Schmidt, Torsten Schmidt and Lina Zwick for valuable comments that helped to improve this manuscript. – All correspondence to: Philipp Breidenbach, RWI, Hohenzollernstr. 1-3, 45128 Essen, Germany, e-mail: [email protected] 1. Introduction Duringthepastdecades,Germanregionalairportshaveexpandedtoaremarkableextent. RegionalpolicymakersinvestedmillionsofEurosinairportfacilities,aimingtoascertainthat thosefulfilltherequirementsofmodernairportsinaneraofarapidlygrowingaviationmarͲ ket. Contrary to those ambitious expectations, today nearly all German regional airports deͲ pendonsubstantialsubsidiestocovertheirannuallosses.SincetheEuropeanUniondecided thatthesesubsidiesviolateEuropeancompetitionlaw,itwillbeprohibitedafter2024touse themtocoveroperationallosses.Theselegalrequirementswillcauseexistentialproblemsfor anumberoftheseregionalairports. Opponents of the subsidies feel vindicated by this decision, since in their assessment reͲ gionalairportswillneverfindtheirnichebetweentheestablishedlargeairportsandwillnever reachprofitability.Proponentsoftheairportsarguethatthenarrowfocusonthedirectlosses failstorecognizetheirimportanceforregionaldevelopment.Theyemphasizepositivespillover effects for the surrounding industry, alleging that service industries and highͲtech branches particularlybenefitfromairportproximity(Sheard,2014,Brueckner,2003andButton/Taylor, 2000).Theargumentofstrongemploymenteffectsisusedtojustifythecontinuedoperation oftheseairports(Robertson,1995). Itisdifficulttoanalyzetheseairporteffectsempirically,sincetypicallytheexpansionofreͲ gionalairportsistheoutcomeofeconomicandpoliticaldeliberationsinarealͲworldcontext, and not the result of an analytical experiment. Therefore, the question what counterfactual development an airport region would have realized without the expansion cannot be anͲ sweredwithease.Onthecontrary,asthemanyattemptsattheeconometricevaluationofthe (regional) growth effects of infrastructure investments demonstrates (e.g. Aschauer,1989), theproblemsofreversecausalityandunobserved(regional)heterogeneityarealmostubiquiͲ tous(e.g.Mukkala/Tervo,2013,Buttonetal.2010andGreen,2007). ThispaperexploitsanabruptchangeintheregulationofEuropeanaviationthatcanbeinͲ terpreted as a quasiͲexperiment to overcome this difficulty. Specifically, the deregulation of theEuropeanaviationmarketin1997ledtoasubstantiallyredesignedaviationmarket(GraͲ ham,1995),providingaparticularlystrongincentivetoexpandGermanregionalairports.DeͲ signedtostrengthencompetitionontheairlinemarket,thisreformcausedanincreasingdeͲ mandfortakeͲoffandlandingslotsatairports.Establishedinternationalairportswerenotable not serve this increasing demand and, consequently, more airlines turned to operate from regionalairports. Contrarytoinvestmentsdrivenbypositiveregionaldevelopments,thisreformthusledto investments which were set by exogenous changes in the structure of the aviation market (Graham, 2010, Barrett, 2000) and can therefore be regarded as a (quasiͲ)experiment. The paper documents that several airports indeed invested extensively to prepare their regional airportsfortheneedsofmodernandinternationalairlinesandpassengers.Furthermore,the location of German airports is closely linked to German military history since most of them Ͷ wereconvertedfrommilitarytocivilianuseinthepast(Behnen,2004).Theiroriginallocation followedmilitarystrategiesinsteadofeconomicreasoning(Cidell,2003).Thesecircumstances facilitate an analysis of exogenous airport expansions on the basis of a differenceͲinͲ differencesͲapproach(DiD)whichovercomesregionalheterogeneityproblems. Tothebestofmyknowledge,thisisthefirstpaperscrutinizingtherecentlydiscussedefͲ fectofregionalairportsexpansionsusinganexogenouseventasidentificationstrategy.2The resultsaresobering.Theestimationsstartwiththeapplicationofabasicmodel,ignoringany potentialendogeneityproblems,whichcomparesprosperitylevelsinregionswithandwithout airports. Such a preliminary approach indeed suggest airport induced regional prosperity. However,whenendogeneityproblemsaretakenintoaccountbyexploitingtheEuropeandeͲ regulationof1997,thiseffectvanishes.Thisresultisconfirmedbyvariousrobustnesschecks. There is simply no evidence that spillovers spreading out from such expansions of regional airportscouldjustifytheiroverwhelmingsubsidization. Theremainderofthepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section2summarizestheexistingliterͲ ature,emphasizingendogeneityissuesandtheinstitutionalsettingsofthederegulation.SecͲ tion3describesthedatasetandoutlinestheDiD.Theresultsandvariousrobustnesschecks arepresentedinsection4,and,finally,section5concludes. 2. EUaviationmarketreformassourceofexogenousvariation 2.1. Existingliteratureandconceptualchallenges ProponentsofregionalairportsarguethatairportsactasadrivingforceofregionaldevelͲ opment, because airports tend to increase income and employment in the local economy (ELFAA,2004).Theytypicallyfocusonthreetransmissionchannels(seeButton,2010forfurͲ thersubdivisions):(i)directeffects,realizedthroughemploymentandinvestmentsattheairͲ port,(ii)indirecteffects,inthechainofsuppliersofgoodsandservicesrelatedtotheairport, and (iii)induced effects which comprise the surplus of employment through spending of diͲ rectlyandindirectlyemployedindividuals.Besidethesethreechannels,airportsaresupposed tohaveacatalyticeffectbyimprovingproductivityandattractingeconomicandtouristicactivͲ ities(e.g.EUCommitteeoftheRegions,2004,Cezanne/Mayer,2003). However,obtainingempiricalevidenceforsuchairporteffectsisachallengingtask.ArguaͲ bly,thesimplestmethodforexaminingwhethertheexistenceofanairportaffectsgrowthin the surrounding region – a direct comparison of growth between airportͲ and nonͲairportͲ regions – will lead to biased estimates, due to omitted regional heterogeneity. Even though onemightbeabletocontrolforawiderangeofobservablevariables,thisidentificationstratͲ egywouldstillbepronetosufferingfromunobservableheterogeneity,inparticularembodied insuchregionalpreͲconditionswhicharelikelytobecorrelatedwiththeexistenceofanairͲ 2 TheUSaviationderegulationact(1978)hasbeenexploitedasexogenousgivenchangesofairservices(BloninͲ gen/Cristea(2012)butasshownbelow,thisreformdidnotmarkcomparablechangesforregionalairports. ͷ port.Sincethelocationofanairportisnotrandom,theremightbehigherprobabilityforthe erection of an airport in a prospering region. In this context, the application of fixed effects estimations in panel data frameworks (Islam,1995) is of little help since the existence of an airportisafixedeffectitself. Focusingonairportactivities,suchasflights,passengersorcargodevelopment(Floridaet al., 2012) helps to introduce further variation in the dataset. However, as long as increased activities do not have an experimental exogenous character, it is not possible to distinguish whetherimprovingregionalconditionsinfluenceairportactivityasfoundbyGoetz(1992)and Dobruszkesetal.(2011)orviceversaassuggestedbytheairportproponents.Specifically,this problemoccursiffutureregionaldevelopmentisanticipatedandairportexpansionsarebased upon it. In this case, time series analyzes, e.g., provided by Green (2007), Mukkala/Tervo (2013)orButton/Yuan(2013)cannothelptoidentifyaleadingandafollowingprocess.3 Morepromisingidentificationstrategiescanbederivedfromexogenousevents.Brueckner (2003) and Sheard (2014)4, for instance, apply the concept of instrumental variables in their analyses.However,findingexogenouseventsorproperinstrumentswhichareabletopredict airport size but do not correlate with regional circumstances is a challenging task. BloningͲ en/Cristea(2012)considertheUS“AviationDeregulationact”5in1978whichwasendorsedto promotecompetitionintheaviationmarketasanexogenousevent.ActingundermarketpresͲ sureafterthereform,airlinesfocusedtheiractivitiesonthecentralairportssincesubsidiesfor peripheralconnectionswerecut.Theseshiftsinitiatedremarkableincreasesanddecreasesin the various airports’ activities (Burghouwt/Hakfoort, 2001), exogenous from the respective regional development. Based on the deregulation act, Bloningen/Cristea(2012) observe that increasingairportactivitiesaffectpopulationgrowth,percapitaincomeandemploymentposiͲ tively. Although, their paper offers a promising methodological approach for the evaluation of generalairporteffectsthesetupislessrelevantfortheparticularexaminationofregionalairͲ porteffects.Theirstudyisrestrictedtotheexaminationofexogenouslyinducedgrowthofbig airportsincentralmetropolitanareas.Bydefinition,regionalairports(inthescopeofthispaͲ per) are rather small and they are located in less central areas. Therefore, effects obtained 3 Beside this, the applied Granger causality tests do only give a hint for potential economic causality (MukkaͲ la/Tervo,2013). 4 Sheard(2014)exploitstheUS1944NationalAirportPlan,whichmarksanexogenouscomponentofthesizeof today’sairportswithoutbeingdirectlyinfluencedbythelaterdevelopmentoftheUScities. 5 SincethepreͲreformaviationmarketintheUSdidnotreallyholdasanexampleforanopenmarketbutrather offeredahighdegreeofgovernmentalregulations,thederegulationactledtosubstantialshiftsinthemarketstrucͲ ture. The market situation was described by obstacles such as peripheral connections with higher governmental subsidiesthanattainedticketturnaroundsontheonehandandother'hotconnections'whereonlyalimitednumͲ ber of flights were allowed although there was a demand for much more flights on the other hand (BloningͲ en/Cristea,2012).Sincethissetupwasnotsustainablefortherapiddevelopmentoftheaviation,USgovernment passedaradicalreformofthesystemfor1978.SeeBloningen/Cristea(2012)foradetaileddescriptionofthisreͲ form. from the US deregulation act cannot be translated to the expansion of regional airports and thegrowtheffectsofthesurroundingregions. 2.2. EUaviationmarketreform EncouragedbytheapparentsuccessofmarketderegulationsintheUS,in1983theEuroͲ peanCommissionstartedaderegulationinitiative,theSingleEuropeanAviationMarket(GraͲ ham,1997).ThepostͲreformperiodintheUSdemonstratedhowenhancedcompetitioncould leadtoanincreaseofsuppliersandflightsand,decreasingprices.ThederegulationoftheEuͲ ropean market was split into three separate steps. The first two steps were implemented in 1988 and 1990 (Graham,1995) and were characterized by rather small changes such as the permissionofbilateralintraͲEUagreements,thevalidityofcompetitionrulesfortheaviation andimplementationofthreeboundedfarezoneswhichallowedticketstobesuppliedbelow thestandardminimumfares(Schenk2004:95ff).6 Substantialchangesinthestructurewereinitiatedbythethirdstep(Graham,1997).This included the harmonization of the airline licensing processes, entire liberalization of ticket faresandtheabolitionofcapacityregulationsbetweenmemberstates.TheinvolvedsuspenͲ sionofallcabotageͲrestrictions7openedthemarketforarangeofnewairlines(Schenk2004: 98).ThesetrendschangedthemarketdramaticallysinceasubstantialnumberofairlinesenͲ tered the German market as further competitors, leading to an increased number of flights (see Thompson, 2002 for France). Nevertheless, slots (for departures and arrivals), ground operationservicesandbookingsystemsrepresentedabottleneckfortheoperationofincreasͲ ing traffic. National carriers enjoyed grandfathering rights for the slots and services without convincing“useitorloseit”rules(Schenk,2004).Thus,theappropriateaccessofnewcompetͲ itorstotheestablishedairportswashinderedandtheyhadtodiverttheirbusinesstoregional airports. TheincreasednumberofcompetitorsandtheshortageofslotsatestablishedairportsproͲ vided strong incentives to regional policy makers to engage into airport expansion. Graham (1997) documents substantial benefits for regional airports and for the newly emerging reͲ gional airlines.8 Furthermore, the reform incentivized regional policy makers to expand the airportsrightin1997whennewairlinesenteredthemarketandincreasedthedemandforthe services of regional airports to conduct their operations. Thus, the reform forms a (quasiͲ )experiment,sincethetimingoftheexpansionswasdeterminedbylegislation,notbyeconomͲ icconsiderations.Germanyimplementedtheregulationaslateaspossibleinthebeginningof 1997,foryearsafteritpassedEuropeanCouncilin1993.ThislongperiodensuresthatplanͲ nershadenoughtimetopreparetheairportsfortheincreasingdemandforservices.MoreoͲ 6 SeeGraham(1995/1997)fordetaileddescriptionofthefirsttworeformstepsandSchenk(2004)fortheirconͲ creteimplementationintheGermancase. 7 CabotagerestrictionsinterdicttheprovisionofanationalroutebynonͲdomesticairlines.Oninternationalroutes onlythedomesticairlinesfromoneoftheconnectedcountriesisallowedtoprovidetheroute. 8 Section3providesevidenceforactualinvestmentsatGermanregionalairportsinthistime. ver, preͲreform adjustment of the airͲservices (Ashenfelter’s Dip problem, Ashenfelter 1978) couldnotoccursincetherestrictiveregulationswerestillintact. Thescopeofthereformstrengthensitsinterpretationasanexogenouseventwithrespect to regional development. The European Commission intended to intensify competition beͲ tweenairlines(Graham,1998),whiletheincentivesforregionalairportexpansionswereonly sideeffectsofthereform.Thiscontrastswithregionalpolicymeasureswhicharespecifically designed to compensate for disadvantages of the targeted regions. As Behnen (2004) points out,thereformdidnotonlycausearevolutionintheskybut,especiallyinGermany,alsoon theground. Moreover, the initial location of German regional airports is also quite unrelated to the economic circumstances surrounding them, since most of the today’s regional airports have served as military bases in some stages of their existence, before they were converted into civilianuse(Behnen,2004).Therefore,theirlocationwasnotdrivenbytheeconomicneedsof aregionorfavorableeconomicpreͲconditions(Cidell,2003),butwasratherbasedonmilitary strategiesandtheassociateddistributionoftheairforce. Takentogether,themilitarybackgroundoftheinitiallocationsofregionalairports,theenͲ compassingscopeofthereformwhichdidnotintendtosupporttheregionalairports,andthe exogenousimpetusleadingtotheinvestmentsintoregionalairportexpansionformthreearͲ gumentswhichfacilitatetheexaminationofthecausaleffectsofairportexpansionsonregionͲ alprosperity. 3.DataandIdentificationStrategy TheDiDapproachprovidesasoundidentificationstrategyfortheevaluationofthepotenͲ tialregionalgrowtheffectswhichmighthavebeeninducedbythederegulationoftheaviation market.Sincethedataset9containsannualinformationonGermancounties(NUTS3level)for theperiodfrom1991to2008,thepreͲ1997yearsserveaspreͲtreatmentperiodandthelatter astreatmentperiod.Thedemarcationintotreatmentandcontrolregionsismorechallenging. Obviously,thoseregionswitharegionalairportareregardedasthetreatmentgroup.Asthe researchquestionfocussesontheeffectsforregionalairportsanddetailedreactionsofestabͲ lished(international)airportsonthederegulationremainunclear,suchregionswithinternaͲ tionalairportsareomittedintheevaluation.10 Forthispurpose,thedistinctionbetweeninternationalandregionalairportshastobedeͲ fined.ThemaindefinitionofregionalairportsinthispaperreliesonthepreͲreformpassenger figuresprovidedbytheGermanAirportAssociation(ADV).Allthoseairportswithlessthanone millionpassengersin1996areincludedinthetreatmentgroupasregionalairports.ThisarbiͲ 9 EconomicvariablesaretakenfromtheFederalInstituteforResearchonBuilding,UrbanAffairsandSpatialDeͲ velopmentBBR(2009)andBBR(2011). 10 Possiblytheywerealsopositivelyaffectedbythereformandgainedhigherefficiencyoftheirtraffic. ͺ trarydefinitionisextensivelytestedintherobustnesscheckswhichcontainvaryingthresholds from0.5millionto5millionpassengersperyear.Lesspromisingdistinctionsaretheairports’ legal permissions (which are subdivided into international and regional permissions)11 or the categorization of its members provided by the ADV itself (which suffers from selfͲselection problems).12GermancountieswithoutaregionaloraninternationalairportserveastheconͲ trolgroup. ThegrowthofGDPperlaborforce(GDPpl)isthemostpromisingindicatorwhichcancapͲ turetherangeofassumedspilloversfromregionalairportstoregionalprosperity.Therefore, thegrowthofnominalGDPperlaborforceisusedasthemainoutcomevariable.13Sincethe GDPperlaborforcemayalsohavesomeminorshortcomings14furtherestimationsintheroͲ bustnesschecksareappliedwiththegrowthoftotalGDP,GDPpercapitaandemploymentas dependentvariables. In contrast to the majority of airport evaluations which exploit terms of air services (Allroggen/Malina,2014),thispaperfocussesonthepureexistenceofinfrastructurecaptured inacrosssectionaltreatmentdummy(ai)turning1iftheregionhasaregionalairportand0 otherwise.Thetimedummy(tt)indicatesthepostͲtreatmenteraandtheirinteraction(DiDit) marksthevariableofinterest,theDiDindicator.StartingwithapureDiDasfirstestimation,a varyingsetofcontrols(xkit)issubsequentlyincludedtoprovideanindicationoftherobustness oftheestimates. An increasing set of control variables can account for regional heterogeneity will tend to improvetheprecisionoftheestimates.However,especiallyinthecontextofregionaleconomͲ ics, the inclusion of controls is problematic as they might themselves be an outcome of the treatment (Angrist/Pischke (2008)15, Becker etal.2014). In the context of airport expansions this is relevant for, e.g., regional investments which might be increased by the expansions. Developments of these “bad controls” which are driven by the treatment may bias the estiͲ mated effect of the treatment on the outcome variable, due to the correlation between the badcontrolandtheoutcomevariable. The lagged level of population, population density and employment are included as conͲ trols.Furthermore,thelaggedlevelofthelefthandsidevariable,thelevelofGDPperlabor force,isincluded.Thisisstandardformodelsbasedonneoclassicaltheorybutposesproblems 11 However, the offered flight destinations do not justify this distinction. International flights are also provided from those airports which are legally defined as regional airports. See destinations of, e.g., DortmundͲWickede (http://www.dortmundͲairport.com/f2a0c5cf806929ea/passengersͲvisitors) 12 Therobustnesschecksalsoincludeestimationsdefiningthethelegallydefinedregionalairportsastreatment group. 13 GDPcanonlybeprovidedoncurrentpricelevelsincethereisnoinformationonpriceindicesforthedeflation onthechosenlevelofregionalentities(Destatis,2015) 14 Underthestrictassumptionofafixedcapitalstock,theGDPperlaborforcemaydecreasebytheincreaseof employment. 15 Angrist/Pischke(2008)denotethosecontrolvariablesas“badcontrols”. ͻ regardingitsimplicitdynamiccomponent.Sincetheoutcome(gyi,t=ln(yi,t)Ͳln(yi,tͲ1))correlates withthemodel’serrorterm(ߝit),theregressor(yi,tͲ1) alsocorrelateswiththeerrorterm,leadͲ ing to biased estimates (see Nickell 1981 or Baltagi2008 for an overview). As Bruno (2005) shows,thedynamiccorrectedfixedeffectestimatorbasedonaninitialBlundell/Bond(1998) estimationprovidessatisfactoryresultsforrathershortsamplesperiods.Resultsbasedonthis estimationmethodarepresentedintheappendix. Theestimationsarebasedonthefollowingmodel. K gyi ,t G1ai G 2tt G 3 DiDit E1 ln( yi ,t 1 ) ¦ E k ln( xi ,t 1,k ) H i ,t (1) k 2 wherei=1,…,NisthecrossͲsectionalandt=1,…,Tisthetimedimension,ɴkandɷ1,ɷ2andɷ3are regression coefficients to be estimated, and ɸi,t is an independent and identically distributed errorterm(i.i.d.).AlleconomicvariablesaretakenfromBBR(2011).Estimationisbasedonthe modelbeingtransformedintofirstdifferences,therebyexcludingtheindividualai 'gyi ,t K G 2 'tt G 3 'DiDit E1' ln( yi ,t 1 ) ¦ E k ' ln( xi ,t 1, k ) ui ,t (2) k 2 withuit=ɸi,tͲɸi,tͲ1. Thehostcountyofanairportmightnotbetherightdelineationforcapturingtheairport’s economiccontribution.Typically,airportsarenotlocatedinthecenterofcounties;thisespeͲ cially holds for airports located in bigger cities. They are rather situated in the periphery of citiesorinadjacentcounties.Thus,simplyconsideringthehostcountiesofairportsasrelevant regional unit is not appropriate, since their economic effects spread out to adjacent regions (i.e.,spilloverscrosscountyborders).ThisproblemistackledbydefiningimputedairportreͲ gions which deliberately construct buffers around the airport’s reference point (see Paloyo etal.2010fordetails). Thechosenradiusof15kilometersroughlyrepresentsthemeanradiusofGermancounͲ ties.Thus,thebuffersizeisrathersmall.16Thepaper concentratesontheregionaleffectsin the immediate proximity of an airport. Furthermore, since many local municipalities provide largesharesofthesubsidiesandtheyjustifythisbythepositivespillovers,suchsmallbuffers are the right demarcation for the objective of this paper. Thus, hinterland effects are intenͲ tionallydisregardedin thisapproach. WhetherairtransportsupplyhasapositiveoverallimͲ pactonGermanseconomyisaseparatequestion. Theeconomiccharacteristicsoftheseairportbuffersaredefinedbythevariablesofthose administrativecountieswhicharelocatedinthebuffer.Precisely,thebuffervariablesaredeͲ fined by the withinͲbuffer weighted means, with the respective spatial shares serving as 16 Thefollowingresultsarenotsensitivetoavariationofbuffersizesfrom10to30kilometer(withexceptionof the30kmͲdefinition,notshowninthepaper,butavailableuponrequest). ͳͲ weights.Sincenearlyallairportbuffersconsistofmorethanonecounty(theonlyexceptionis HannoverͲLangenhagen), the number of observations is much smaller than the number of regions.17 Although DüsseldorfͲWeeze and Memmingen are regional airports today, they are ignoredintheempiricalanalyses,sincetheydidnotserveasregionalairportsin1997.Weeze was opened in 2003 while civilian use in Memmingen started in 2004. All these limitations reduce the original sample size of 413 German counties to 271 observed regional units. An overviewontheregionalandinternationalairportsaswellasamapwiththebuffersisprovidͲ edinFigureA.1intheappendix. DescriptivestatisticsofthesampleareprovidedinTable1.ItappearsthatregionswithareͲ gionalairportandthosewithoutthesefacilitiesdonotdiffersubstantially.ThemeanGDPper laborforcegrowthis0.002percentagepointshigherintheairportregions.18Theairportand nonͲairportregionsdonotdiffersubstantiallyinalmostallthevariablemeans,asthetͲtestin thelastcolumndocuments.Onlythelogofpopulationandemploymentdisplayhighermeans intheairportregions. Table1:DescriptiveStatisticsforairportandnonͲairportregions GDP(growth) GDPpl(growth) GDPpc(growth) GDPpl (x103) GDPpc (x103) ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) Density (x103) Airportregions(24) Mean Min/ (Std.Dev.) Max 0.030 Ͳ0.041/ (0.039) 0.218 0.027 Ͳ0.036/ (0.037) 0.211 0.033 Ͳ0.040/ (0.039) 0.222 48.725 21.502/ (8.333) 68.455 23.431 7.429/ (6.399) 37.273 4.258 1.807/ (0.884) 5.739 5.007 2.821/ (0.793) 6.525 0.006 0.000/ (0.009) 0.066 NonͲAirportregions (247) Mean Min/ (Std.Dev.) Max 0.028 Ͳ0.260/ (0.039) 0.252 0.025 Ͳ0.262/ (0.039) 0.294 0.029 Ͳ0.241/ (0.040) 0.261 49.804 17.702/ (8.650) 90.099 23.608 6.230/ (9.071) 76.558 4.100 2.915/ (0.540) 6.861 4.893 3.649/ (0.546) 7.184 0.010 0.001/ (0.033) 1.027 tͲstatistic Ͳ0.505 Ͳ0.621 Ͳ1.065 1.808* Ͳ0.102 Ͳ9.198*** Ͳ7.904*** 2.061** Note:AllvariablesaretakenfromBBR(2011).***,**,*denotesignificantdifferences atthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand10%Ͳlevel. 17 The buffers are also constructed for the international airports which are ignored in the further course of the analyses. 18 CloserexaminationoftheminimalgrowthratesinnonͲairportregionsshowthattheseareoutlierswhichare supposedtobeartificiallyconstructedbycorrectionsoftheofficialstatistics. ͳͳ TheinvestmentactivitiesatGermanregionalairportsreflecttheincentiveswhichthedereguͲ lationoftheaviationmarketprovidedtoregionalpolicymakers.Varioustypesofinvestments were undertaken; airports expanded their terminals or runways and better connections to publictransportwereestablished.Inaddition,someairportsprovidedregularairͲserviceswith scheduledflightsforthefirsttimeafterthereform.Onlyforthreeofthe24regionalairports, therearenoexplicitinvestmentsfoundfor1997andtheadjacentyears.19 4. Results Toprovideafirstimpression,resultsfromabasicestimationsetupdemonstratewhether airportregionsdisplayahigherGDPperlaborforcethannonͲairportͲregions.20Notethatthe motivationfortheseestimationsismerelytoillustratetheendogeneitybiasofsuchasetupin comparisontothesubsequentidentificationstrategies,basedonthe(quasiͲ)experiment.FoͲ cusingonthispreferableidentificationapproach,aDiDmodelisestimatedafterthecommon trend assumption is tested. These baseline estimations are followed by various robustness checkstoconsiderthreecrucialissuesoftheidentification:First,theAshenfelter’sDipprobͲ lem, second the sensitivity to changes of the definition and the spatial demarcation of the treatmentgroupandthirdchangingdefinitionsofthecontrolgroup.Anumberofsecondary testsarepresentedintheappendix. 4.1. Estimationresults ThefirstimpressioninTable2showsthattheexistenceofanairport–unconstrainedon internationalorregional(column(i)and(ii))–clearlycorrelateswiththelevelofregionalGDP perlaborforce.Thespecificationincludingcontrolvariables(column(ii))suggeststhattheGDP per labor force is 3.5% higher compared to regions without an airport. Omitting all internaͲ tionalairportsfromthesamplereducesthiseffectto1.9%incolumn(iv),althoughitremains significant.However,thesefindingscanonlydrawanincompletepicture,sincetheestimation approachdisregardsanyendogeneityproblems. 19 Excludingthesethreeregionsfromtheestimationsdoesnotchangethefollowingresults. 20 IncontrasttosubsequentDiDͲestimationsbasedonthegrowthoftheGDPperlaborforce,thisestimationis based on the its level values since potential airport induced growth effect faded in after their opening and they shouldshowupinhigherlevelvaluestoday. ͳʹ Table2:PooledͲOLSwithoutDiDforallandregionalairports DependentVar: LogofGDPpl Airport WestGermany ln(Population) ln(PopulationͲ Density) StateͲDummies CountyͲtype TimeDummies No.ofRegions No.ofObs. Allairports (i) (ii) 0.040*** 0.035*** (0.009) (0.004) 0.347*** (0.011) 0.005*** (0.001) 0.036*** (0.003) N Y N Y N Y 287 287 4845 4495 RegionalAirports (iii) (iv) Ͳ0.015 0.019*** (0.009) (0.004) 0.158*** (0.012) 0.002* (0.001) 0.032*** (0.003) N Y N Y N Y 271 271 4624 4288 Note: ***,**,* denote significance at the 1%Ͳ, 5%Ͳ and 10%Ͳlevel. Robust standard errorsclusteredoncountyͲlevelinparentheses. TosupporttheapplicationoftheDiDapproach,Figure1displaysthegrowthoftheGDP per labor force separately for treated and nonͲtreated regions. The basic assumption of the DiDimpliesthatbothgroupswouldhavedevelopedequallyintheabsenceofthetreatment. Sincethisisanassumptiononthecounterfactualitcannotbestatisticallytested.AvisualinͲ spection of Figure1 shows only minor level differences in the preͲtreatment development which can be captured by regional fixed effects (Angrist/Pischke, 2008), therefore the DiD seemstobeasuitablemethod. This impression is corroborated by “placebo regressions” with altered definitions of the treatment in the robustness tests. Note further, that a simple “before and after” analysis of airportregionsinsteadofaDiDwouldprovidemisleadingresultssinceitonlyfocusesonthe highergrowthofGDPperlaborforceamongairportregionsafterthereformwithoutaccountͲ ingforthequitesimilardevelopmentofthecontrolregionsovertime. ͳ͵ Figure1:CTA,TreatmentandnonͲTreatmentgrowthrate (AnnualGDPperlaborforcegrowthrate) ThemainresultsinTable3donotshowastatisticalsignificantexpansioneffectofthereͲ gionalairportsongrowth.Thevariableofinterest(DiDͲestimator)whichaccountsforreformͲ inducedgrowthremainsinsignificant.Thegrowingnumberofcontrolvariablesdoesnothave anyinfluenceonthestatisticalsignificanceoftheDiDcoefficient.Theseresultsareconfirmed byrathersimilarresultsinTableA.1whichconsiderthedynamiccorrectionofthefixedeffect modelasproposedbyBruno(2005).SincethedynamiccorrectioninitiallyatartsfromaBlunͲ dellͲBond (1998) estimation which also faces some shortcomings, e.g., potentially imprecise estimators in a rather small crossͲsectional (Bruno 2005), and since the dynamic component seemsnottobiasstandardfixedeffectestimations,thefurtherestimationsarebasedonthe standardfixedeffectmodel. ͳͶ Table3:DiDͲFixedeffectsforregionalairports Dep. Variable: GDPplgrowth DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged Constant TimeDummies No.ofRegions No.ofObs. (i) Ͳ0.004 (0.008) Ͳ0.023*** (0.002) (ii) Ͳ0.004 (0.004) 0.004*** (0.001) Ͳ0.160*** (0.008) 0.092*** (0.017) (iii) Ͳ0.003 (0.005) 0.002 (0.002) Ͳ0.149*** (0.009) 0.054** (0.022) 0.084*** (0.026) Ͳ0.000 (0.001) (iv) Ͳ0.002 (0.003) 0.003 (0.002) Ͳ0.295*** (0.012) Ͳ0.079*** (0.022) 0.126*** (0.032) Ͳ0.001** (0.001) 0.042*** (0.002) N 271 4352 0.261*** (0.076) N 271 4352 Ͳ0.035 (0.105) N 271 4288 0.844*** (0.134) Y 271 4288 Note:***,**,*denotesignificanceatthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand10%Ͳlevel.RobuststandarderͲ rorsclusteredoncountyͲlevelinparentheses. 4.2. RobustnessTests Potential weaknesses of the main results are tested in the following robustness checks. First, the estimations of a DiD might be biased since reform effects are anticipated and preͲ reformadjustmentstothenewscenerytakeplace(Ashenfelter’sDip).AlthoughairportplanͲ nersdidanticipatethereformtheycouldnotbenefitfrompreͲreformadjustmentssincethe market situation could not change notably before the deregulation. Therefore, an earlier inͲ vestment did not lead to advantages in the preͲreform period. Nevertheless, construction measures which were required before the deregulation to provide adequate infrastructure maybiastheresults.Thisbiasmaybetwofold,ontheonehandreformͲinducedconstructions mayhavecausedpreͲreformgrowthandthereforebiastheexpansioneffectdownwards.On theotherhand,airportoperationsmayhavebeenreducedduetosuchconstructionsinpreͲ reformyearsleadingtoanupwardbiasoftheestimatedexpansioneffect. TheAshenfelter’sdipproblemconcernsthepreͲreformyears.Sincetheexpansioneffects may have taken time to spread out and to attract airport activities (and since some investͲ mentswerenotcompletedintime)thefirsttwopostͲtreatmentyearsareexcludedinfurther estimations.TheresultsofthetwostrategiesarepresentedinTable4,column(i)and(ii)focus ontheAshenfelter’sdipandexcludetheyears1996and1995,thelattercolumnsexcludethe years 1997 and 1998. Table 4 shows that the estimated DiD coefficients remain insignificant whenexcludingtheseyears. ͳͷ Table4:DiDͲFixedeffectswithexcludedyears (DependentVariable:GrowthofGDPperlaborforce) Exclusionof… DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged Constant TimeDummies No.ofGroups No.ofObs. 1996 Ͳ0.005 (0.004) 0.009*** (0.003) Ͳ0.296*** (0.013) Ͳ0.082*** (0.024) 0.132*** (0.033) Ͳ0.001** (0.001) 0.824*** (0.137) Y 271 4024 1995&1996 Ͳ0.007 (0.005) 0.019*** (0.004) Ͳ0.305*** (0.013) Ͳ0.077*** (0.026) 0.133*** (0.035) Ͳ0.001* (0.001) 0.830*** (0.140) Y 271 3760 1997 Ͳ0.002 (0.003) 0.016*** (0.003) Ͳ0.293*** (0.012) Ͳ0.080*** (0.024) 0.128*** (0.033) Ͳ0.002*** (0.001) Ͳ0.293*** (0.012) Y 271 4021 1997&1998 Ͳ0.002 (0.003) 0.010*** (0.003) Ͳ0.291*** (0.012) Ͳ0.075*** (0.024) 0.134*** (0.032) Ͳ0.002*** (0.001) Ͳ0.291*** (0.012) Y 271 3754 Note:***,**,*denotesignificanceatthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand10%Ͳlevel.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredon countyͲlevelinparentheses. Assecondrobustnesscheck,thetreatmentgroupisvariedbythedefinitionofthethreshͲ old between regional and international airports. Since the assumption to treat all airports (listedbytheADV)withatmostonemillionpassengersperyearasregionalairportsmightbe crucial, this threshold is varied from 0.5 million to 5 million passengers in columns (i)Ͳ(v) in Table5.Sincethoseairportregionswithpassengernumbersabovethethresholdareexcluded from the estimations, the number of included regions and observations increase with an inͲ creasing threshold. The last column restricts the treatment group on the legally defined reͲ gional airports independent of the respective passenger numbers.21 The results in Table 5 showthattheDiDcoefficientisrobusttothedifferentdefinitionsofthetreatmentgroup. 21 TheestimationsinTable4coverthesamecontrolsascolumn(iv)inTable3.Thus,resultsofcolumn(ii)(1milͲ lionpassengers)equalscolumn(iv)inTable3. ͳ Table5:DiDͲFixedeffectsforregionalairports Dep.Variable: GDPplgrowth DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged Constant TimeDummies No.ofRegions No.ofObs. TreatmentͲThreshold:Max.passengersperyear 0.5million 1million 2million 2.5million 5million Ͳ0.002 Ͳ0.003 Ͳ0.003 Ͳ0.004 Ͳ0.004 (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) 0.009*** 0.003 0.003 0.003 0.009*** (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.003) Ͳ0.296*** Ͳ0.296*** Ͳ0.294*** Ͳ0.296*** Ͳ0.296*** (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) Ͳ0.082*** Ͳ0.082*** Ͳ0.080*** Ͳ0.082*** Ͳ0.081*** (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) (0.022) 0.131*** 0.131*** 0.130*** 0.132*** 0.132*** (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) Ͳ0.001** Ͳ0.001** Ͳ0.001** Ͳ0.001** Ͳ0.001** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) 0.834*** 0.837*** 0.830*** 0.830*** 0.824*** (0.133) (0.133) (0.132) (0.132) (0.131) Y Y Y Y Y 270 271 276 278 279 4288 4320 4368 4400 4416 Legally defined Ͳ0.005 (0.004) 0.009*** (0.003) Ͳ0.294*** (0.012) Ͳ0.079*** (0.023) 0.131*** (0.031) Ͳ0.001** (0.001) 0.810*** (0.131) Y 264 4160 Note:***,**,*denotesignificanceatthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand10%Ͳlevel.Robuststandarderrorsclusteredon countyͲlevelinparentheses. Furthermore,thesizeofthebufferswhichmarkthetreatedregionsaroundtheairportsis varied.TheradiusofthetreatmentͲbufferisdoubled(30km)toobservepotentialeffectsina larger group of regions. Based on this enlarged buffer size, the DiD coefficient turns slightly negative (presented in column (i) of Table6). In addition, one might be concerned that the stable unit treatment value assumption (SUTVA) is violated in the estimations setup. If the regions within treatment buffer affect the outcome of the adjacent control regions by some negativeorpositivespillovers,thecoefficientofthetreatmentestimatorisbiased. To overcome this problem, again the 15 km buffers are considered as treatment group. But,topreventadirecttransitionfromtreatmenttocontrolgroup,allregionswithinthe30 kmbufferbutoutsidethe15kmbufferareignoredandneitherconsideredasmembersofthe treatment nor the control group. Thus, spillovers from treated regions cannot directly influͲ ence the control group (column (ii) of Table6). This estimation does not show a significant result. ͳ Table6:DiDͲFixedeffectsvariedbuffersize (DependentVariable:GrowthofGDPperlaborforce) (i) (ii) Excludedring 30kmbuffer from15Ͳ30km Ͳ0.005* Ͳ0.005 (0.003) (0.003) 0.005* 0.012*** (0.003) (0.003) Ͳ0.295*** Ͳ0.004 (0.012) (0.005) Ͳ0.080*** Ͳ0.150*** (0.022) (0.013) 0.127*** 0.054 (0.031) (0.033) Ͳ0.001** 0.087** (0.001) (0.035) 0.849*** 0.814*** (0.135) (0.200) Y Y 271 154 4288 2426 DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged Constant TimeDummies No.ofGroups No.ofObs. Note:***,**,*denotesignificanceatthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand 10%Ͳlevel.RobuststandarderrorsclusteredoncountyͲ levelinparentheses. Third,onemightbeconcernedthatthebroaddelineationofthecontrolgroupwhichcomͲ prises all German regions without an airport is inappropriate. As discussed in section 2, airͲ portsmightbelocatedinregionswithspecificeconomiccharacteristics.Hence,ifthesecharͲ acteristics determine the probability for having an airport on the one hand and the growth expectations over the treatment period on the other hand, the empirical strategy, may lead astray.Ineconometricterms,thecharacteristicsofthecontrolvariablesmaynotoverlapbeͲ tweenthetreatmentregionsandacriticalmassofcontrolregionsinthesample.Accordingto thisconcern,controlregionswhichdiffersubstantiallyfromtheairportregionsintheirregionͲ alcharacteristicswouldhavetobeexcludedfromtheestimation. In the spirit of a matching approach, a propensity score is estimated based on a probit model. K pi ¦E k ln( zi ) vi (3) k 1 Onthelefthandside,thedummypiindicatesifaregionhasanairport(pi=1)ornot(pi=0).On therighthandside,ziindicatesaverybroadsetofregionalcontrols, ߚkaretherelatedcoeffiͲ ͳͺ cientstobeestimatedand,ʆiisani.i.d.errorterm.Sincevariationovertimedoesnotreally offerfurtherinformation,themodelisestimatedwithobservationsoftheyear1996,thelast preͲreformobservation.Theestimatedoutcomes( p̂ )indicatearegionalprobabilityforhostͲ inganairport.Therangeoftheestimatedairportprobabilities( p̂ )oftheairportregionsdeͲ cides which regions enter the control group.22 Only those nonͲairport regions with a ( p̂ ) within the range of ( p̂ ) of airport regions are considered in the control group. Regions withanexceptionallylowprobabilityforhavinganairportareexcluded. Table7:ProbitfortheAirportprobability (DependentVariable:AirportDummy) DependentVar.: AirportDummy ln(GDP) ln(GDPpw) ln(GDPpl) Positivemigration ln(Population) ln(Density) WestGermany Constant CountyTypes FederalStateDummies Lowest p̂ ofapt.region Highest p̂ ofapt.region No.ofObs (i) 20.465** (8.762) Ͳ1.935 (1.981) Ͳ16.391* (8.529) 1.046** (0.458) Ͳ0.564** (0.257) Ͳ19.591** (8.785) Ͳ0.205 (1.121) Ͳ16.706*** (5.971) Y Y 0.015 0.975 287 Note: ***,**,* denote significance at the 1%Ͳ, 5%Ͳ and 10%Ͳlevel. Robust standard errors in parentheses. AsTable7shows,therangeofpredictedairportprobabilities( p̂ )forairportregionscover aspectrumfrom1.5%to99.8%.Thisresultsuggeststhatthereisbasicallynoregionwhichhas 22 Togiveanexample,ifthelowestpredictedairportprobabilityofanairportregionis50%,allthosecontrolreͲ gionswithaprobabilitybelow50%areexcludedfromthefollowingDiDestimation. ͳͻ norealisticprobabilityforhostinganairport.Thus,thebroadselectionofthecontrolgroups posesnoproblems.23Thisfindingsupportstheargumentthatthemilitarybackgroundofmost airportsismuchmoreimportantforairportlocationthananyeconomicconsiderations. Furtherrobustnesschecksareprovidedintheappendix.TableA.2presentstwo“placebo regressions”whichrefertoahypotheticalderegulationeventduringthepreͲtreatmentperiod ignoring all postͲtreatment observations and another hypothetical deregulation event during the postͲtreatment period ignoring all preͲtreatment observations. While an artificial treatͲ ment during the preͲtreatment period strengthens the previously discussed common trend assumption, the latter artificial treatment can rather indicate effects of the treatment which fadeinafteracertaintime.Theyears1994and2000arechosenforthehypotheticalreform. Inbothcases,thecoefficientoftheDiDremainsinsignificant. Toensurethattheseresultsarenotbasedonthelowerproductivityofnewjobscausedby theairportexpansion,regressionswiththegrowthoftotalGDPgrowth,GDPpercapitagrowth andgrowthoftheemploymentasdependentvariablesareappliedandreportedinTableA.3 (column(i)Ͳ(iii)).Noneofthesechangesleadstodivergingfindings.Toavoidthedeterioration oftheaviationmarketafter9/11,thesampleperiodends2001incolumn(iv)whichdoesnot changetheobservedresults. 5. Conclusion The EU Commission has recently announced that subsidization of airports which merely survive due to substantial public support will be prohibited after 2024. Since most of the smallerandregionalairportsinGermanyarecurrentlysubsidized,theyarefacingsevereprobͲ lemsfortheirfutureexistence.Proponentsoftheregionalairportsemphasizetheimportance ofpositivespilloversonemploymentandeconomicgrowththroughouttheregion.Thispaper probes if German regional airports indeed generate a better economic performance in their environment. Investments in infrastructure such as airports are an outcome of economic performance and future economic expectations and, correspondingly, evaluations suffer from the related endogeneityproblems.ThederegulationoftheEuropeanaviationmarketmarksanexogenous event which can be seen as a (quasi)Ͳexperiment for the expansion of regional airports. An increasingnumberofairlinesdemandedfurtheroperationslotsinGermanyandshiftedtothe regionalairports.Andthoseairportspreparedtheirinfrastructurewithmassiveinvestmentsto fulfill the airlines’ requirements, quite independent from the contemporaneous economic conditions. Furthermore,themilitary background ofmostregionalairportsmakestheir locaͲ tionlessdependentontheeconomicconditionsintheirenvironment. Based on the assumed exogeneity of the expansion, a DiD is applied which conducts the period after the reform in 1997 as treatment period. For the spatial definition of the treatͲ 23 TheassociatedDiDwithouttheregionswithaprobabilitybelow1.5%isnotshownhere. ʹͲ ment,regionalbufferswitharadiusof15kmareconstructedaroundtheairports.Ignoringthe possible endogeneity problems would lead to a positive estimation of airport effects on the GDP per labor force. This appears to drive earlier positive findings such as Allroggen/Malina (2014). However, when taking into account the preferred deregulationͲbased identification strategy,theestimatedeffectsarenegligible. A broad set of robustness checks strengthens these findings. The results are robust to a change of the definition of regional airports, various demarcations of the control and treatͲ mentgroups,avoidanceofanAshenfelter’sdipbytheexclusionofyearsaroundthederegulaͲ tion,andchangesofthedependentvariable.Areasonforthesesoberingresultsmightbethe overwhelmingopportunitycostsoftheairportoperation.Sincemanymunicipalitiesspenthigh amountsintheoperationoftheairports,thiscapitalistiedupbytheairportandother–posͲ sibly better investments – are precluded. This overall result is supported by a recently pubͲ lishedreportoftheEuropeanCourtofAuditorsthatdetectedsevereunsuccessfulsubsidized airportͲprojects in southern European countries with sobering costͲbenefit relations (EUCA 21/2014). NotethattheevidencepresentedheredoesnotsuggestanyconclusionsregardingtheefͲ fects of international airports. It may be the case that airports need to exceed a certain thresholdtofadeoutspillovers.Furthermore,thehighdensityofairportsinGermanymaybe areasonfortheresults,sincefurtherbenefitsofanexpandedairportmightberatherlowina denseairportnetwork.Besidestheadvancesoftheappliedidentificationstrategy,thismight beafurtherexplanationforthedifferingfindingsinthispapercomparedtoexistingliterature forothercountries. Basedontheeconomiceffects,thispaperdoesnotconfirmconcernsofregionalpoliticians thatregionswillsufferonceairportsubsidieswillbecut.Sincetheexpansionofairportshad nopositiveeffects,adownscalingofactivitiestowardssustainableairportswithoutsubsidiesis not supposed to have major negative effects on the surrounding municipalities. In addition, theprovisionofbetterregionalairtransportinfrastructuredoesnotseemtobeapromising instrumenttostimulategrowthinlaggingregions. ʹͳ References Allroggen,F.,&R.Malina,2014.Dotheregionalgrowtheffectsofairtransportdifferamong airports?.JournalofAirTransportManagement,37,1Ͳ4. Angrist,J.D.,&J.S.Pischke,2008.Mostlyharmlesseconometrics:Anempiricist'scompanion. Princetonuniversitypress. ArbeitsgemeinschaftDeutscherVerkehrsflughäfen(ADV),2015,Verkehrszahlen–Archiv. Onlineavailable:http://www.adv.aero/verkehrszahlen/archiv/ Aschauer,D.A.,1989.Ispublicinfrastructureexpenditureproductive?.JournalofMonetary Economics,23,pp.177–200. Augurzky,B.,Bauer,T.K.,&Schaffner,S.(2006).CopaymentsintheGermanHealthSystemͲ DoTheyWork?.RWIDiscussionPapers:43. Baltagi,B.(2008).Econometricanalysisofpaneldata(Vol.1).JohnWiley&Sons. Barrett,S.D.,2000.AirportcompetitioninthederegulatedEuropeanaviationmarket.Journal ofAirTransportManagement,6(1),13Ͳ27. BBR(FederalOfficeforBuildingandRegionalPlanning),2011.LaufendeBeobachtungendes BundesinstitutsfürBauͲ,StadtͲundRaumforschung,variousissues.Bundesamtfür BauwesenundRaumordnung,Bonn. BBR(FederalOfficeforBuildingandRegionalPlanning),2009.Siedlungsstrukturelle Kreistypen.Publishedonline:http://www.bbsr.bund.de. Becker,S.O.,Boeckh,K.,Hainz,C.,&L.Woessmann,2014.TheEmpireIsDead,LongLivethe Empire!LongͲRunPersistenceofTrustandCorruptionintheBureaucracy.TheEconomic Journal.(onlinefirst) Blonigen,BruceA.&Cristea,AncaD.,2012.AirportsandUrbanGrowth:Evidencefroma QuasiͲNaturalPolicyExperiment(No.w18278).NationalBureauofEconomicResearch. Brueckner,J.K.2003.Airlinetrafficandurbaneconomicdevelopment.UrbanStudies40(8): 1455Ͳ1469. Bruno,G.S.,2005.EstimationandinferenceindynamicunbalancedpanelͲdatamodelswitha smallnumberofindividuals.StataJournal,5(4),473. Burghouwt,G.,J.Hakfoort,2001.TheevolutionoftheEuropeanaviationnetwork,1990– 1998,JournalofAirTransportManagement,Volume7,Issue5,Pages311Ͳ318 Button,K.J.,Doh,S.andYuan,J.,2010.Theroleofsmallairportsineconomicdevelopment, JournalofAirportManagement,4,pp.125–136. Button,K.&Taylor,S.,2000.Internationalairtransportationandeconomicdevelopment. JournalofAirTransportManagement6:209Ͳ222. Button,K.,&Yuan,J.,2013.Airfreighttransportandeconomicdevelopment:anexamination ofcausality.UrbanStudies,50(2),329Ͳ340. ʹʹ Cezanne,W.,andA.Mayer,2003.FlugplatzalsWirtschaftsfaktorͲMöglichkeitenundFormen derLandeplätzealsWirtschaftsfaktor,AnalysederimLandvorhandenenSituation. CommitteeoftheRegions,2004.OwnͲinitiativeopinionoftheCommitteeoftheRegionson ‘LowͲcostairlinesandterritorialdevelopment’.OfficialJournaloftheEuropeanUnion. (2004/C318/02).Brussels Cidell,J.,2014.Theroleofmajorinfrastructureinsubregionaleconomicdevelopment:an empiricalstudyofairportsandcities.JournalofEconomicGeography Cidell,J.,2003.Theconversionofmilitarybasestocommercialairports:existingconversions andfuturepossibilities.JournalofTransportGeography11,93–102. Destatis,2015.RegionaldatenbankDeutschland.ErläuterungBruttoinlandsprodukt, Bruttowertschöpfung.PublishedOnline:https://www.regionalstatistik.de/genesis/online EuropeanLowFaresAirlineAssociation,2004.LiberalizationofEuropeanAirTransport:The BenefitsofLowFaresAirlinestoConsumers,Airports,RegionsandtheEnvironment. Brussels GoetzA.R.1992.AirpassengertransportationandgrowthintheU.S.urbanSystem,1950Ͳ 1987.GrowthandChange23:218Ͳ242. Graham,B.,Guyer,C.,1999.Environmentalsustainability,airportcapacityandEuropeanair transportliberalization:irreconcilablegoals?.JournalofTransportGeography7,165–180. Graham,B.,1998.Liberalization,regionaleconomicdevelopmentandthegeographyof demandforairtransportintheEuropeanUnion.JournalofTransportGeography,6(2), 87Ͳ104. Graham,B.,1997.RegionalairlineservicesintheliberalizedEuropeanUnionsingleaviation market.JournalofAirTransportManagement,3(4),227Ͳ238. GrahamB.,1995.GeographyandAirTransport.Wiley,Chichester. Green,R.2007.Airportsandeconomicdevelopment.RealEstateEconomics35:91Ͳ112. FrédéricDobruszkes,MoritzLennert,GillesVanHamme,2011.Ananalysisofthe determinantsofairtrafficvolumeforEuropeanmetropolitanareas,JournalofTransport Geography,Volume19,Issue4,Pages755Ͳ762 Mawson,J.,1997.AirtransportliberalizationintheEuropeanUnion:anassessment.Regional Studies,31(8),807Ͳ812. MukkalaK.,TervoH.,2013.Airtransportationandregionalgrowth:whichwaydoesthe causalityrun?.EnvironmentandPlanningA45(6)1508–1520 Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica: Journal of the EconometricSociety,1417Ͳ1426. Nijkamp,P.,Geenhuizen,M.,1997.Europeantransport:challengesandopportunitiesfor futureresearchandpolicies.JournalofTransportGeography5,4Ͳ11. ʹ͵ Paloyo,A.R.,Vance,C.,&Vorell,M.2010.Theregionaleconomiceffectsofmilitarybase realignmentsandclosuresinGermany.DefenceandPeaceEconomics,21(5Ͳ6),567Ͳ579. Robertson,J.A.W.1995.Airportsandeconomicregeneration,JournalofAirTransport Management,Volume2,Issue2,June1995,Pages81Ͳ88 Sheard,N.,2014.Airportsandurbansectoralemployment.JournalofUrbanEconomics,80, 133Ͳ152. Thompson,I.,2002.Airtransportliberalisationandthedevelopmentofthirdlevelairportsin France,JournalofTransportGeography,Volume10,Issue4,December2002,Pages273Ͳ 285 VanPraag,B.M.S.andB.E.Baarsma,2005.UsingHappinessSurveystoValueIntangibles: TheCaseofAirportNoise.TheEconomicJournal,115:224–246. Vickerman,R.,Spiekermann,K.,Wegener,M.,1999.Accessibilityandeconomicdevelopment inEurope.RegionalStudies33:1Ͳ15. ʹͶ TableA.1:CorrectedDiDͲFixedeffects(Bruno,2005) Dep. Variable: GDPpllevel DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged TimeDummies No.ofRegions No.ofObs. (ii) Ͳ0.006 (0.005) 0.008*** (0.002) 0.899*** (0.005) 0.109*** (0.01“) N 271 4352 (iii) Ͳ0.003 (0.005) Ͳ0.011*** (0.002) 0.916*** (0.006) 0.023 (0.017) 0.175*** (0.025) Ͳ0.000 (0.001) N 271 4288 (iv) Ͳ0.003 (0.004) 0.003 (0.003) 0.761*** (0.008) Ͳ0.084*** (0.018) 0.196*** (0.025) Ͳ0.001 (0.001) Y 271 4288 Note:***,**,*denotesignificanceatthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand10%Ͳlevel.RobuststandarderͲ rorsclusteredoncountyͲlevelinparentheses. ʹͷ TableA2:PlaceboRegressions(DiDͲFixedeffects) (DependentVariable:GrowthofGDPperlaborforce) DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged (i) Hypothetical Treatmentin1994 (excludingt>1996) Ͳ0.007 (0.006) 0.010*** (0.004) Ͳ0.434*** (0.021) Ͳ0.097 (0.060) 0.672* (0.388) Ͳ0.620 (0.418) (ii) Hypothetical Treatmentin2000 (excludingt<1997) 0.001 (0.003) 0.058*** (0.004) Ͳ0.327*** (0.020) Ͳ0.056** (0.028) Ͳ0.004 (0.042) Ͳ0.001 (0.001) Constant TimeDummies No.ofGroups No.ofObs. 4.779 (4.314) Y 271 1056 1.531*** (0.166) Y 171 3232 Note: ***,**,* denote significance at the 1%Ͳ, 5%Ͳ and 10%Ͳlevel. RobuststandarderrorsclusteredoncountyͲlevelinparentheses. ʹ Ͳ0.005 (0.005) 0.008*** (0.003) Ͳ0.290*** (0.014) Ͳ0.220*** (0.025) 0.283*** (0.037) Ͳ0.001* (0.001) 0.627*** (0.148) Y 271 4288 Dep.Var.GDPpc growth Dep.Var.GDP growth Ͳ0.004 (0.005) 0.008*** (0.003) Ͳ0.293*** (0.014) Ͳ0.202*** (0.025) 0.219*** (0.039) Ͳ0.001* (0.001) 0.883*** (0.152) Y 271 4288 (ii) (i) (iii) Dep.Var. Employment growth Ͳ0.002 (0.003) 0.005*** (0.001) 0.002 (0.006) Ͳ0.122*** (0.010) 0.092*** (0.016) 0.000 (0.000) 0.039 (0.067) Y 271 4288 Ͳ0.001 (0.003) 0.020*** (0.004) Ͳ0.377*** (0.016) Ͳ0.103*** (0.033) 0.227*** (0.051) Ͳ0.003*** (0.001) 0.736*** (0.237) Y 272 2384 Skippedafter 2001 (iv) (vi) BiggestPassenͲ RegionalAirports gersurplus(10 legallydefined Apt) Ͳ0.005 Ͳ0.011*** (0.004) (0.003) 0.009*** 0.009*** (0.003) (0.003) Ͳ0.294*** Ͳ0.293*** (0.012) (0.013) Ͳ0.079*** Ͳ0.079*** (0.023) (0.023) 0.131*** 0.128*** (0.031) (0.032) Ͳ0.001** Ͳ0.002*** (0.001) (0.001) 0.810*** 0.816*** (0.131) (0.134) Y Y 264 257 4160 4072 (v) Note:***,**,*denotesignificanceatthe1%Ͳ,5%Ͳand10%Ͳlevel.RobuststandarderrorsclusteredoncountyͲlevelinparentheses. Dep.Variable: GDPplgrowth(or seecolumn headline) DiDͲestimator PostͲTreat ln(GDPpl) lagged ln(employment) lagged ln(Population) lagged ln(Density) lagged Constant TimeDummies No.ofGroups No.ofObs. TableA.3:Variousrobustnesscheck(DiDͲFE) FigureA.1:Airportandtherespectivebufferregions Altenburg Augsburg Bayreuth BraunschweigͲWolfsburg Dortmund ErfurtͲWeimar FrankfurtͲHahn Friedrichshafen Hof Karlsruhe KasselͲCalden Kiel Lübeck Magdeburg Mönchengladbach Münster Neubrandenburg Paderborn Rostock Saarbrücken Schwerin Siegerland StralsundͲBarth Zweibrücken • • • • • • • • • • • • • BerlinͲSchönefeld BerlinͲTegel Bremen Dresden Düsseldorf FrankfurtamMain Hamburg Hannover Köln/Bonn Leipzig/Halle München Nürnberg Stuttgart InternationalAirports RegionalAirports • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • •